Introduction
The Philips curve was developed by William Phillips in the 1950s. It is a graphical representation of the relationship between inflation and unemployment. The curve suggests that as unemployment decreases, inflation increases, and vice versa. This theory is based on the idea that when there is an increase in overall demand, workers’ wages will also go up. The increase in wages will then push up prices, thereby resulting in inflation. The Philips curve was initially developed as an empirical observation. However, it has become an accepted part of macroeconomic theory, and is used by governments and central banks to guide their economic policies.
The Phillips Curve Model
The Phillips curve model suggests that when the economy is operating at full capacity, there is a tight trade-off between inflation and unemployment. At this point on the curve, any decrease in unemployment rates can only be achieved by increasing inflation. Conversely, in a situation of lower than full capacity, the curve is flatter, indicating that there is less of a trade-off between the two variables.
In this model, the short-run Phillips curve shows a negative relationship between the rate of unemployment and inflation. This means that as the rate of unemployment decreases, the rate of inflation increases and vice-versa. The long-run Phillips curve, however, shows no relationship between the two variables, indicating that in the long run, a decrease in the rate of unemployment has no effect on inflation.
The limitations of the Phillips Curve
The Phillips curve suggests that there is an inverse relationship between unemployment and inflation. However, in some countries, especially those with rigid economic policies, the relationship is not so straightforward. For example, in Germany and Japan, unemployment has decreased without any corresponding increase in inflation. This indicates that the Phillips curve does not always provide an accurate representation of the relationship between inflation and unemployment.
In addition, the model does not take into account other factors that can influence inflation and unemployment. For example, changes in productivity, exchange rates and wages are not taken into account in the model.
Conclusion
The Philips curve is a model that attempts to show the relationship between inflation and unemployment. It suggests that as unemployment falls, inflation rises. However, in some cases, the relationship between the two variables is not so straightforward, and the model does not take into account other influencing factors. Therefore, while it is a useful tool to guide economic policy, the Philips Curve should not be used as a definitive guide to inflation and unemployment.